July 30, 2012 <Back to Index>
PAGE SPONSOR |
Thorstein Bunde Veblen, born Torsten Bunde Veblen (July 30, 1857 – August 3, 1929) was an American economist and sociologist, and a leader of the so-called institutional economics movement. Besides his technical work he was a popular and witty critic of capitalism, as shown by his best known book The Theory of the Leisure Class (1899). Veblen is famous in the history of economic thought for combining a Darwinian evolutionary perspective with his new institutionalist approach to economic analysis. He combined sociology with economics in his masterpiece, The Theory of the Leisure Class (1899), arguing there was a basic distinction between the productiveness of
"industry," run by engineers, which manufactures goods, and the
parasitism of "business," which exists only to make profits for a
leisure class. The chief activity of the leisure class was "conspicuous consumption",
and their economic contribution is "waste," activity that contributes
nothing to productivity. The American economy was therefore made
inefficient and corrupt by the businessmen, though he never made that
claim explicit. Veblen believed that technological advances were the
driving force behind cultural change, but, unlike many contemporaries,
he refused to connect change with progress. Although Veblen was sympathetic to state ownership of
industry, he had a low opinion of workers and the labor movement and
there is disagreement about the extent to which his views are
compatible with Marxism. As a leading intellectual of the Progressive Era,
his sweeping attack on production for profit and his stress on the
wasteful role of consumption for status greatly influenced socialist
thinkers and engineers seeking a non-Marxist critique of capitalism.
Experts complained his ideas, while brilliantly presented, were crude,
gross, fuzzy, and imprecise; others complained he was a wacky
eccentric. Scholars continue to debate exactly what he meant in his
convoluted, ironic and satiric essays; he made heavy use of examples of
primitive societies, but many examples were pure invention. Veblen was born in Cato, Wisconsin, of Norwegian American parents who had immigrated from Norway. He spent the majority of his youth on his family farm in Nerstrand, Minnesota; the farmstead is now a National Historic Landmark.
Although Norwegian was his first language, he learned English from both
neighbors and at school, which he began at the age of 5. His
family was highly successful and placed great emphasis on education and
hard work, all of which undoubtedly contributed to his later scorn for
what he termed “conspicuous consumption” and waste of the gilded age. These
settlements were little Norways, oriented around the religious and
cultural traditions of the old country . He broke away by attending a
Yankee school, Carleton College Academy (now Carleton College) in
Northfield, Minnesota; he was lucky to study with young John Bates Clark (1847 - 1938), who later became the nation's foremost economist and was a leader in the new field of neoclassical economics. Veblen did graduate work at Johns Hopkins University under Charles Sanders Peirce, the founder of the pragmatist school in philosophy; he took his Ph.D. in 1884 at Yale University with a dissertation on "Ethical Grounds of a Doctrine of Retribution." He was a student of philosopher Noah Porter (1811 - 1892) and economist/sociologist William Graham Sumner (1840 - 1910). Perhaps the most important intellectual influences on Veblen were Charles Darwin and Herbert Spencer,
whose work in the last half of the 19th century sparked an enormous
interest in the evolutionary perspective on human societies. Veblen married fellow Cornellian Ellen Rolfe in 1888; it was an unhappy marriage that finally ended in divorce in 1911. Upon graduation from Yale, Veblen was unable to obtain an academic job, partly due to prejudice against Norwegians, and
partly because most universities considered him insufficiently educated
in Christianity — most academics at the time held divinity degrees. Veblen returned to his family farm — ostensibly to recover from malaria — and spent six years there reading voluminously. In 1891 he left the farm, to study economics as a graduate student at Cornell University under James Laurence Laughlin. In 1891 after years of working on the farm he finally obtained his first academic appointment at the new University of Chicago,
which overnight had become a world class university in many fields. He
was promoted to assistant professor in 1900 and edited the prestigious Journal of Political Economy, while conversing with such intellectuals as John Dewey, Jane Addams and Franz Boas. He published two of his best known books, The Theory of the Leisure Class (1899), and The Theory of Business Enterprise (1904). The books made him famous overnight for their ridicule of businessmen. In 1906, he moved to Stanford University.
He soon left, perhaps because of blatant adultery, or because the
faculty and administration distrusted a man they saw as a poor teacher,
a nasty colleague and a political radical. Veblen
reflected many of his views in his personal habits. To wit: Veblen's
house was often a mess, with unmade beds and dirty dishes; his clothes
were often in disarray; he was an agnostic; and he tended to be
extremely blunt and rude while dealing with other people. In 1911, Veblen joined the faculty of the University of Missouri, where he had support from Herbert Davenport,
the head of the economics department. Veblen disliked the local town
but remained until in 1918 he moved to New York to begin work as an
editor of The Dial. In 1919, along with Charles Beard, James Harvey Robinson and John Dewey, he helped found the New School for Social Research (known today as The New School). From 1919 through 1926 Veblen continued to write and be involved in activities at The New School. The Engineers and the Price System was written during this period. Veblen proposes a soviet of engineers in one chapter in The Engineers and the Price System. According to Yngve Ramstad, this
work's view that engineers, not workers, would overthrow capitalism was
a "novel view". Veblen invited Guido Marx to the New School to teach
and to help organize a movement of engineers, by such as Morris Cooke; Henry Laurence Gantt, who had died shortly before; and Howard Scott. Cooke and Gantt were followers of Taylor's Scientific Management. Scott, who listed Veblen as on the temporary organizing committee of the Technical Alliance, perhaps without consulting Veblen or other listed members, later helped found the Technocracy movement. Veblen had a penchant for socialism and
believed that technological developments would eventually lead toward a
socialistic organization of economic affairs. However, his views
regarding socialism and the nature of the evolutionary process of
economics differed sharply from that of Karl Marx; while Marx saw
socialism as the ultimate goal for civilization and saw the
working class as the group that would establish it, Veblen saw
socialism as one intermediate phase in an ongoing evolutionary process
in society that would be brought about by the natural decay of the
business enterprise system and by the inventiveness of engineers. Daniel Bell sees an affinity between Veblen and the Technocracy movement. Janet Knoedler and Anne Mayhew demonstrate
the significance of Veblen's association with these engineers, while
arguing that his book was more a continuation of his previous ideas
than the advocacy others see in it. In 1927 Veblen returned to the property that he still owned in Palo Alto and died there in 1929. His death came less than three months before the momentous crash of the U.S. stock market, which heralded the Great Depression. Veblen developed a 20th century evolutionary economics based upon Darwinian principles and new ideas emerging from anthropology, sociology, and psychology. Unlike the neoclassical economics that
was emerging at the same time, Veblen described economic behavior as
both socially and individually determined and saw economic organization
as a process of ongoing evolution. This evolution was driven by the
human instincts of emulation, predation,
workmanship, parental bent, and idle curiosity. Veblen wanted
economists to grasp the effects of social and cultural change on
economic changes. In The Theory of the Leisure Class, the instincts of emulation and predation play a major role. People,
rich and poor alike, attempt to impress others and seek to gain advantage through what Veblen coined "conspicuous consumption"
and the ability to engage in “conspicuous leisure.” In this work Veblen
argued that consumption is used as a way to gain and signal status.
Through "conspicuous consumption" often came "conspicuous waste," which
Veblen detested. In The Theory of Business Enterprise, which was published in 1904 during the height of American concern with the growth of business combinations and trusts,
Veblen employed his evolutionary analysis to explain these new forms.
He saw them as a consequence of the growth of industrial processes in a
context of small business firms that had evolved earlier to organize
craft production. The new industrial processes impelled integration and
provided lucrative opportunities for those who managed it. What
resulted was, as Veblen saw it, a conflict between businessmen and
engineers, with businessmen representing the older order and engineers
as the innovators of new ways of doing things. In combination with the
tendencies described in The Theory of the Leisure Class, this conflict resulted in waste and “predation” that served to enhance
the social status of those who could benefit from predatory claims to
goods and services. Veblen
generalized the conflict between businessmen and engineers by saying
that human society would always involve conflict between existing norms
with vested interests and new norms developed out of an innate human
tendency to manipulate and learn about the physical world in which we
exist. He also generalized his model to include his theory of
instincts, processes of evolution as absorbed from Sumner, as enhanced
by his own reading of evolutionary science, and Pragmatic philosophy
first learned from Peirce. The instinct of idle curiosity led humans to
manipulate nature in new ways and this led to changes in what he called
the material means of life. Because, as per the Pragmatists, our ideas
about the world are a human construct rather than mirrors of reality,
changing ways of manipulating nature lead to changing constructs and to
changing notions of truth and authority as well as patterns of behavior
(institutions). Societies and economies evolve as a consequence, but do
so via a process of conflict between vested interests and older forms
and the new. Veblen never wrote with any confidence that the new ways
were better ways, but he was sure in the last three decades of his life
that the American economy could have, in the absence of vested
interests, produced more for more people. In the years just after World
War I he looked to engineers to make the American economy more
efficient. In addition to The Theory of the Leisure Class and The Theory of Business Enterprise,
Veblen’s monograph "Imperial Germany and the Industrial Revolution",
and his many essays, including “Why Is Economics Not an Evolutionary
Science,” and “The Place of Science in Modern Civilization,” remain
influential. In
spite of difficulties of sometimes archaic language, caused in large
part by Veblen’s struggles with the terminology of unilinear evolution and of biological determination of social variation that still dominated social thought when he began to write, Veblen’s work remains relevant, and not simply for the phrase “conspicuous consumption”.
His evolutionary approach to the study of economic systems is once
again in vogue and his model of recurring conflict between the existing
order and new ways can be of great value in understanding the new
global economy. The handicap principle of evolutionary sexual selection is often compared to Veblen's “conspicuous consumption”. Veblen, as noted, is regarded as one of the co-founders (with John R. Commons, Wesley C. Mitchell, and others) of the American school of institutional economics. Present day practitioners who adhere to this school organise themselves in the Association for Evolutionary Economics (AFEE) and the Association for Institutional Economics (AFIT). AFEE gives an annual Veblen - Commons award for work in Institutional Economics and publishes the Journal of
Economic Issues. Some unaligned practitioners include theorists of the
concept of "differential accumulation". Veblen is cited in works of feminist economists. Veblen’s work has also often been cited in treatments of American literature. One of Veblen's Ph.D. students was George W. Stocking, Sr., a pioneer in the emerging field of industrial organization economics. |